sábado, 4 de diciembre de 2021

sábado, diciembre 04, 2021

The Fed must abandon average inflation targeting

Why should failures in the past drive monetary policy in the future?

Willem Buiter 

When he announced the adoption of AIT last year, Fed chair Jay Powell emphasised the inflation expectations channel © Kevin Dietsch/Getty


The most egregious mistake made by a leading central bank in the pursuit of price stability has been the US Federal Reserve’s adoption of “average inflation targeting” in August 2020.

The 2 per cent annual inflation target for the personal consumption expenditure price index, introduced in 2012, applied to the inflation rate in any given period and the anticipated inflation rates for all future periods. 

AIT — even the flexible variety favoured by most members of the Federal Open Market Committee — calls for a deliberate overshooting following episodes of below-target inflation, so as to ensure that average inflation rates are closer to the target.

A 2020 statement by the FOMC commits it to achieving “inflation that averages 2 per cent over time”. 

But members of the Committee take different views of what that would mean in practice.

Atlanta Fed president Raphael Bostic considers targeting four- to eight-year moving averages of assorted inflation metrics. 

His counterpart at the Cleveland Fed, Loretta Mester, mentions five-, six- or seven-year moving averages for PCE inflation, or even a fixed starting point rather than a moving average. 

St Louis Fed chief James Bullard considers a five-year window to be realistic, while Charles Evans of the Chicago Fed mentions an asymmetric five-year averaging, with no correction required for past overshooting of the inflation target.

All these versions of AIT could mean many years of deliberately generated and quite unnecessary above-target inflation.

Arguments for AIT generally start with the correct observation that, because of the extremely low level of the neutral real rate of interest, the effective lower bound on the Fed’s policy rates has become a binding constraint. 

As a result, inflation in the US has been below target consistently from the start of the financial crisis until the first quarter of 2021. 

Fear of the so-called Japanification of the US economy — a combination of deflation and anaemic growth — has been driving the Fed’s decisions until the recent overshooting of the inflation target put monetary policy tightening back on the agenda.

It is bound to be the case that, when the economic system operates at the ELB for significant chunks of time, even the most effective pursuit of the conventional inflation target will generate an average inflation rate that is below target. 

Following the AIT approach of deliberately overshooting the inflation target (during periods when the ELB does not constrain monetary policy) is indeed likely to result in an average inflation rate closer to the target. 

But it would do so at the cost of higher average absolute deviations (and higher average squared deviations) from the target rate. 

Better to be below target when you cannot be on target and on target when you can be, than to be below target when you cannot be on target and above target when you could be on target!

AIT is a form of price-level targeting. 

Yet basic economics teaches us that the price level is irrelevant. 

Actual and anticipated future inflation rates matter. 

Inflation is a tax on nominal assets and distorts relative price signals. 

Anticipated future inflation influences expected returns on a range of assets.

Proponents of AIT care about past inflation, which can be indirectly relevant for monetary policymakers if there are causal relationships between it and the objectives of monetary policy. 

Contracts with lagged indexation clauses are one such channel. 

Past inflation can influence expectations of future inflation which can in turn drive actual current and future inflation. 

When he announced the adoption of AIT last year, Fed chair Jay Powell emphasised the inflation expectations channel.

But there are other drivers of expected future inflation: past, present, and anticipated future money growth, forward guidance, expected and unanticipated changes in the monetary and fiscal policy regime, supply side developments, among many others. 

Even poorly informed economic agents will learn to identify episodes when the ELB is a binding constraint on Fed policy.

Except in unlikely special cases, the role of past inflation in driving current and future inflation expectations, and through them actual current and future inflation, will not call for anything like an AIT rule.

The choice of average inflation targeting is economically illiterate. 

Why should unintended and mostly unavoidable inflation targeting failures in the past justify future deliberate failures? 

And the cost of adopting AIT could be serious: future periods of unnecessary, deliberate above-target inflation. 

It is time to get rid of this potentially costly nonsense.


The writer is a visiting professor at Columbia University

0 comments:

Publicar un comentario