jueves, 19 de mayo de 2011

jueves, mayo 19, 2011

The Economy Is Sliding Into a Stagflationary Spiral


This article discusses the current path our economy is taking. While most economists believe the Q1 GDP stumble was a temporary blip in an ongoing recovery, I believe it is the beginning of a downward trend of economic stagnation and inflation. The root of this is the Fed's attempts to inflate the economy into recovery. If you look at it this way it explains why current economic performance is so weak. This is a complex topic and it needs a thorough explanation. That is why this is a long, comprehensive article. But I back up my statements with current data and if you persist to the end, it will reward you with what I think is a proper explanation of our future.

* * * * *

According to most economists the Q1 GDP stumble was a blip, something we shouldn't worry about because the economy is still on track for recovery. They are reacting to the preliminary report that GDP fell to 1.8% in Q1, down from 3.1% in Q4 2010. They are also rather unbothered by increasing prices at the wholesale and consumer level.



Another way to look at it is that the economy is being harmed by monetary inflation and we are seeing massive distortions in the economy as a result of this intentional Fed policy. The economy is responding in predictable ways that will lead to less real growth, price inflation and more problems. I think this is the correct way of looking at things and Q1 is not a temporary blip on the road to recovery.

One would think that with all the money that the Fed is pumping into the economy through quantitative easing, GDP would rise. After all, GDP at its basic level is merely a measure of dollars spent in the economy and if you just throw more dollars into the mix, the result would be that GDP would rise (along with prices) just because of that. But more spending doesn't necessarily measure real growth in the economy; with monetary inflation only an account of the physical production of goods can measure that. But the conventional wisdom is that GDP is a measure of an economy's health and if everyone believes that, then policies public and private are based on it and it's worth following.

But the question persists: why is the economy not performing up to the expectations of policy makers?

What is happening is that that economic growth is stalling and industrial production, manufacturing, non-manufacturing, durable goods production, retail sales and employment is flattening-to-declining. The reason is monetary inflation, which is an expansion of money supply according to the classic Austrian theory definition.
Rising prices are just an effect of monetary inflation along with other negative consequences.

The consequence of money expansion is a negative for the economy, despite what the Keynesians, Monetarists and Chairman Bernanke say. It only serves to distort the economy, cause more destruction of real savings/capital through malinvestment, increase prices and ultimately results in a decline of economic activity.

Money supply, as measured by the correct index, True (Austrian) Money Supply (TMS), has been expanding. This has been a result of QE and to a lesser extent, some expansion of bank credit.

The following chart measures not only TMS but also M2:

 Courtesy Michael Pollaro, The Contrarian Take

What are these distortions and do we see them in the economy today?

Price Inflation

The headline consequence of monetary inflation is price inflation. It is clear that it is rising.

On Thursday the Producer Price Index came out showing that it went up again and is now at a 6.6% annual rate:




But there is more to it than that. If you break it down and look at the non-seasonally adjusted measure of the production of intermediate goods and crude materials (e.g., steel billets, industrial chemicals), then you get a different picture:





You could argue that this isn't a fair measure because they are not seasonally adjusted, but they are actual numbers and the seasonality adjustments may involve a bit of magic that is sometime questionable.
Friday's Consumer Price Index shows that price inflation at the consumer level, the one that consumers complain about, is rising:




The CPI-U rose 0.4% (Core 0.2%) for the month of April and 3.2% (Core 1.3%) for the last 12 months. According to the BLS report, prices were driven by energy (2.2%), gasoline (3.3%, but 33.1% for last 12 months) and food (0.4%) costs.

Thus by every measure price inflation is increasing. For example, if you don't trust the government's data (it is thought that perhaps they have a stake in keeping it low), you can look at Shadowstats.com's measure or MIT's Billion Price Project:





As you can see reasonable people differ on the level of price inflation, but none of them show it going down.

Export Growth

U.S. growth is being driven by exports and the chief beneficiaries of that are large multinational companies. Caterpillar (CAT), GE (GE) and Intel (INTC) are prominently mentioned as examples of this.
Since the recovery started in the third quarter of 2009, exports have contributed about 1.4 percentage points to the nation's 3.0% annualized growth rate, marking trade's biggest share of growth over an 18-month stretch on record.
The problem is that this trend of manufacturing growth is not spilling over into the rest of the economy, especially to the small companies (less than 250 employees), which employ one-half of Americans. The reason for this is that monetary inflation (fiat money) is a two-edged sword that helps exporters, destroys capital and penalizes consumers.

There is no question that the reason exporters are successful is because the declining dollar is turning the so-called level international playing field into a ski slope for American exporters; they have a substantial monetary advantage in world markets. In the last 12 months, the dollar has declined 9.1%.

Low U.S. interest rates (less attractive to foreign investors), QE and chronic deficit spending (prompting S&P's threatened downgrade of U.S. sovereign debt) have devalued the dollar. While Dr. Bernanke can say with a straight face that the U.S. has a "strong dollar" policy, the world knows that is a lie and their true policy is to devalue the dollar to favor U.S. exporters. The Fed and the administration see exports in terms of an engine of job creation, although that doesn't appear to be working very well for them. What they miss is the greater cost to American consumers of imported goods. While it is true that oil prices are cartelized, the impact of a cheap dollar makes gasoline more expensive for consumers. That has a negative impact on retail spending.

Industrial Production

A close look at the "other" (non-export) economy belies the exports-as-leading-economic-growth trend. The data associated with manufacturing is either flattening or declining in the face of monetary expansion. This is a troubling thing considering how well exporters are doing.

The latest data shows industrial production flattening-to-declining:



The ISM Non-manufacturing Index has been declining for the past two months:



The ISM Manufacturing Index is showing a flattening-to-declining trend.



Durable goods orders are on a declining trend as well.



As DoctoRx reported, the ECRI index for industrial growth has turned negative. They apparently have a flawless (so far) record of forecasting economic cycles, according to the Doc. I have no idea what goes into their proprietary methodology, but here is their chart:




Retail Sales

Retail sales have been flattening as well.



Retail sales' recent "gains" are mostly related to increased spending on gasoline, not retail shopping. Retail sales excluding autos and gasoline in April only increased by 0.2%. Gallup's recent surveys also supports this trend. In fact, they show that upper-income consumer spending has flattened out as well. It does not help that real wages declined 0.3% in April.

Consumer Metrics Institute, whose methodology I do understand, is also reporting that retail sales have fallen off dramatically. "After a week-long pause our Daily Growth Index resumed its movement into record [negative] territory, setting a new all-time low representing a 6.39% year-over-year contraction on May 3, 2011."




Employment

While there is definite improvement in employment, it is still weak and unemployment remains high:



While job creation increased in April (private employment up 268,000), the overall unemployment rate went up to 9% from 8.8%. The Wall Street Journal had an interesting graphic describing the recent report:



We added about 1.2 million jobs in 2010, but there are 13.7 million people still looking for work. Since April of last year, the labor participation rate actually declined from 65.1% to 64.2%.

Then consider this study from USA Today:
A record 18.3% of the nation's total personal income was a payment from the government for Social Security, Medicare, food stamps, unemployment benefits and other programs in 2010. Wages accounted for the lowest share of income51.0% — since the government began keeping track in 1929.
From 1980 to 2000, the percentage of Americans receiving government benefits was 12.5%. A jump to 18.3% is not a good sign as Boomers head into retirement and exercise their claims on Social Security and Medicare.

The Bifurcated Economy

The conclusion of this profusion of charts and data is that while the export sector is thriving because of a de-valued dollar and while Wall Street and the financial sector have been the prime beneficiaries of QE, the rest of the economy is stalling. Considering all of the effort by the Fed from QE and the government's attempts at fiscal stimulus, the economy is still sluggish and if it's growing at all, it is because of the money steroids.

The reason the economy is not growing is that the Fed-government policies themselves are 1) destroying real capital/savings and 2) are tying up capital in unliquidated malinvestments.

Real Capital Destruction

Monetary inflation cannot create wealth. Only production can create wealth. I have discussed this many, many times, but I believe that our policy makers confuse the dollars they print with wealth.

Things are wealth and money just is a means of exchanging some goods or labor for other goods or labor. This is Austrian Theory 101. If you print fiat money, it doesn't create goods or labor, it just allows those who get their hands on it first to bid away goods and labor (wealth) from other producers (and, all things being equal, cause prices to rise). Since the new money was not based on production, someone is getting something for nothing. Because the signals that cheap money sends to borrowers is not based on market realities, but rather time value distorted realities, cheap money leads to the production of goods people don't want. Such as homes.

As we found in our current cycle, capital flowed into housing and some $6 trillion was destroyed (malinvested) in the boom. The bust is merely the process of liquidating malinvestment.

It is difficult to determine how much capital is being consumed by monetary inflation. Instead of trying to figure that out, I look to its effects as evidence that it is occurring. As would be expected, the destruction and resulting shortage of real savings/capital has caused a decline in industrial production, high unemployment, sluggish or declining retail sales, a lack of credit and higher prices.

A good question is that if real savings/capital is being destroyed, why would exporters be successful? The idea being that despite their cheap dollar advantage, if they can't muster the capital, shouldn't they be stagnating? The obvious answer is that they do have sufficient capital to expand. This country has a huge reserve of real savings and not all of was wiped out in the crash. Many of these companies do not need to rely on banks and can fund expansion from retained earnings. Or they can tap into the reservoir of capital through banks and the commercial paper markets.

Malinvestment and Liquidity

The second problem that we face is the slow liquidation of malinvestments.

The prior expansion of money and credit by the Fed (2001 to 2006) created the biggest boom-bust cycle in world history. And we know where the money went: into residential and commercial real estate.

There were two sources of credit that flowed into real estate.

One source was from large banks, pension funds, insurance companies and investment funds. Their loans and investments were mainly funneled into mortgage-backed securities, were divided into tranches and sold worldwide. Most of the residential loans from major housing lenders and the loans for large Class A commercial real estate were packaged and sold this way.

Some of the more creative and riskier financing vehicles involved subprime loans.

The other source was residential and (mostly) commercial real estate loans made by regional and local banks. These loans were not packaged and sold off but were held on their books as portfolio loans. It is these banks that are most affected by the real estate crash.

The big banks were bailed out and had to a great extent offloaded their real estate loans into these mortgage-backed securities.

It's not that they don't have serious problems as a result of the fallout from the crash, including claims related to mortgage backed securities, but they are lending again and their customers, large corporations, are borrowing. No credit crunch there.

It is different at the regional and local banking level. Most of them held on to their bad loans as long as they could to avoid recognizing losses, which would require them to either raise more capital or fail.

The banking regulators have largely facilitated this approach by suspending mark-to-market rules, requiring them to take TARP money, plus other accounting rules.

But these lenders cannot hold back the flood. Both commercial and residential real estate continues to decline in value. There was so much overproduction (malinvestment) that four years after the crash the problem still festers. The result was that these banks tightened up lending standards, were wary of committing to new loans and kept bad projects on life support hoping that things would turn around. Thus the credit crunch. They are the lenders that one-half of American businesses rely on for credit.

But now is there a growing trend to liquidate these investments:
The chasm that once separated banks' marks on nonperforming loans and realized sale prices has been shrinking. At the same time, healthier institutions are more capable of absorbing losses to extricate themselves from their nonaccrual portfolios. Though executives prefer to cite improved pricing — and not a prior aversion to taking charges — the two are often intertwined.
"Managements have had to be a little more realistic that their assets aren't worth par," said Chris McGratty, a KBW analyst who has been cataloging the steady increase in sales.
"The other thing is that the banks are more willing to take the hit from a sale because they've raised capital and they want to put the credit situation behind them."


This is a positive trend, but it will continue to depress real estate prices for some years to come. But as banks clear off their balance sheets, credit will start to loosen up. We are just starting to see some of that now.

Banks, for competitive reasons, have lowered lending standards for commercial and industrial business loans and bank credit is starting to expand. But loan demand is coming mainly from larger to intermediate sized companies and from M&A activity, which means that credit demand from and lending to small businesses is still low and that QE money has been largely for the benefit of Wall Street and the large multinationals.



Consumer credit has been modestly expanding, mainly from auto loans and government-backed student loans:





All this adds up to stagflation.

Outcomes

What does this all mean in terms of the future of the economy?

1. We are in a new phase of monetary expansion that will lead to further destruction of real capital which will result in economic stagnation.

2. Despite the stagnation of the economy, we will see price inflation as long as the Fed keeps pumping up the money supply.

3. For the next two or three years, real estate prices will continue to be depressed as lenders shed bad residential and commercial mortgage loans and REO. Of course, this will have an uneven impact around the country, but areas with the most overexpansion (malinvestment) will have the greatest declines.

4. Banks are repairing their balance sheets and raising capital to meet new capital standards. This will ultimately lead to new credit creation, but in light of the Fed's goal of creating price inflation, it is likely that real production will remain flat but asset prices will eventually take off as people seek inflation hedges.

5. Capital destruction and stagnation will keep unemployment high.

6. It is unlikely that the Fed will raise interest rates or reduce monetary growth as long as we have high unemployment, especially in an election year.

7. The dollar will remain devalued, depending on the relative values of the euro and the RMB. This will continue to favor exporters and harm U.S. consumers.

8. It is unlikely that serious reform of federal spending programs will occur and tax hikes are likely, including a national sales or VAT tax.

9. The debt rating of U.S. Treasurys will decline, increasing the nominal cost of financing the debt.

10. It is likely that we will see further monetization of Treasurys as it becomes more difficult to sell them on the world markets.

11. The cost of financing the deficit will actually go down as rising price inflation will allow the government to pay debt with depreciated dollars.

12. The eurozone will continue to have serious structural problems, starting with Greece and ending with Spain. It appears that it will be difficult to carry out necessary reforms. It will keep the euro under pressure.

13. When inflation gets out of control, Bernanke will resign and a new Volcker will be appointed to increase Fed interest rates, increase reserve requirements and reduce its balance sheet, driving Treasurys and other interest rates way up. Because there are so many "what ifs" here, I am not forecasting a particular time or rate. For example, a Republican presidency and Congress could change the scenario and institute needed drastic reforms, but assuming they win, I still don't see meaningful reforms.

Conclusion

While I appreciate the work of Rogoff and Reinhart (This Time Is Different ...) that credit/monetary cycles are always the same, for our purposes this time is different in the sense that policy makers and many in the financial industry expected this cycle to behave like other recent cycles. That is, the Fed would bail us out and after a bit of nastiness, things would go back to normal.

It hasn't worked out in the way they expected. This is quite evident with our lead policy maker, Chairman Bernanke, that expert on the Great Depression. I would dismiss statements that he and other Fed economists made to the effect that the Fed "saved" the economy.

Instead they just covered the problem over with a big monetary blanket and prayed for rain. The effect is that problems were just papered over and haven't been resolved. That is why we are still experiencing severe problems almost four years later. Fiat money is never a solution.

The size of the boom phase of the cycle is something unprecedented in world history and the level of malinvestment was historic in scope. This is what the policy makers underestimated. As we have discovered, we are stuck in between bust and recovery as banks struggle to liquidate malinvestments and repair their balance sheets, while at the same time the Fed is trying to inflate the way to recovery. We are experiencing the effects of these policies: stagflation.
Which means the Q1 stumble was not just a blip.

This article originally appeared in The Daily Capitalist.

Disclosure: I have no positions in any stocks mentioned and no plans to initiate any positions within the next 72 hours.

0 comments:

Publicar un comentario