jueves, 12 de agosto de 2010

jueves, agosto 12, 2010
Watch China’s coasts, not its currency

By Yukon Huang

Published: August 10 2010 22:45

China’s exchange rate continues to be blamed for global economic imbalances, with the economist Paul Krugman one of Beijing’s staunchest critics. Even after China announced a change in its currency policy in June, Mr Krugman argued that it did notaddress the real issue, which is that China has been promoting its exports at the rest of the world’s expense”. Yet, arguably, it is the Nobel Prize-winning ideas that Mr Krugman developed three decades ago, not currency manipulation, that have led to China’s unparalleled growth.

Deng Xiaoping, the architect of China’s reforms, would almost certainly have disagreed with those who see appreciation of the renminbi as the solution to global trade imbalances. Instead, he would probably have noted that neither is China’s exchange rate a noticeable drag on global growth, nor is it what helped China to develop. It was about the same time that Mr Deng began opening China to the world in 1979 that Mr Krugman began formulating his theories on the “new economic geography”. These showed how economies of scale and declining transport costs encourage concentration of production in certain places, and in turn lead to new trade patterns. It is this process that transformed China into the world’s most efficient producer-cum-exporter of manufactured goods.

Mr Deng initiated a strategy based on the three “Ds” of this new economic theory. China increased the “density” of economic activity by concentrating production in a few coastal cities geared to exports. It cut the “distance” between markets through an expansion of transport services. It undertook to reduce barriers to the movement of goods, helping to eliminatedivisions”.

Deliberateunbalancedgrowth generated huge economies of scale and encouraged some 150m migrant workers to gravitate to the booming commercial centres around Guangzhou, Shanghai and Beijing. Over time, high-technology and export industries relocated to the coast and resource-based and domestically oriented industries established a presence in the interior.

This concentration and specialisation pushed 500m people out of poverty and led to annual gross domestic product growth of 10 per cent. The share of GDP that was traded surged from 10 per cent in 1979 to more than 70 per cent today. This extraordinary transformation was the result of a complex set of policies, with exchange rates having played only a minor role.

For much of this period, China’s exchange rate was seen as overvalued not undervalued. Paradoxically, when China finally did allow the renminbi to appreciate from 2005 to 2008, its trade surpluses grew bigger rather than smaller. Other factorsnotably savings and investment rates – were, and continue to be, the primary determinants of China’s trade balances.

Mr Deng also foresaw that China’s development would eventually reach a turning point. Indeed, forces are now beginning to reshape China’s economic landscape in ways that may resolve the controversial role that China is accused of playing in shaping global trade imbalances – and in turn undo concerns over the issue in the US, and increasingly in Europe too.

Given the fragile global economy, China’s major concern is to maintain rapid growth and lessen the inequality that came with its original unbalanced growth. Urban household incomes are more than three times rural ones – the highest differential in the world – and coastal incomes more than double those in the interior.

To reduce inequality, China will need to increase the share of wages in total income, and favour consumption over investment. This process will be made easier when the distribution of economic activity is more balanced between the coast and inland. More by accident than design, China’s policy of stable exchange rates has nudged along this shift.

Fixed exchange rates have caused large current account surpluses, which in turn have inflated wages and property prices, especially on the coast. Consistent with Mr Krugman’s theories, rising coastal production costs and declining transport costs are motivating companies to relocate inland. With this, income disparities will fall over time. Mr Deng predicted this, suggesting gaps between interior and coastal incomes would widen, then narrow. Today, interior provinces grow faster than coastal ones.

What would be the impact of a major appreciation – as the west frequently calls for – of China’s exchange rate? A one-off appreciation would not encourage companies to move from the coast, because the effect on prices would be neutral rather than differentiated across regions. Indeed, this “shockapproach would be disruptive, with social and political consequences.

A stronger currency earlier in this process would have made it more difficult for the interior to compete. But the process now under way, supported by moves towards flexible exchange rates, will encourage wages and consumption to rise, thereby alleviating trade tensions and reducing China’s income disparities. But America must realise that an excessive focus on China’s exchange rate is not helpful in moving China’s policies in the right direction when other factors matter more. Mr Krugman might note the irony that the accuracy of his older theories may ultimately assuage his more contemporary worries.

The writer is a senior associate at the Carnegie Endowment and former country director for the World Bank in China. His most recent book is Reshaping Economic Geography in East Asia

Copyright The Financial Times Limited 2010.

0 comments:

Publicar un comentario